logo

Title






Saving Communities

Bringing prosperity through freedom,
equality, local autonomy and respect for the commons.

Home

Site Map

Index

New Pages

Contacts

David Ricardo

Ricardo’s Law of Rent

Illustrated and Expanded to Consider Different  Qualities of Labor and Capital

and to show why rent-sharing creates prosperity for all


by Dan Sullivan

Ricardo’s Principles of Political Economy was inspired by Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations, which he sometimes criticized and sometimes elaborated upon. His treatment of rent was inspired by Smith’s chapter, “Of the Rent of Land,” and particularly by this quote:

“The rent of land, therefore, considered as the price paid for the use of the land, is naturally a monopoly price. It is not at all proportioned to what the landlord may have laid out upon the improvement of the land, or to what he can afford to take; but to what the farmer can afford to give.”

Ricardo noted that this was true of rent in Europe, where all the land was thoroughly monopolized, but that it was not true of rent in America, where there were vast amounts of land open for settlement. In such a situation, people would take up the best land first, and have no rent to pay. Rent would slowly arise as the best land was taken up and people had to resort to poorer land. He agreed with Smith that land value was not wealth in the Wealth of Nations sense.

I have already expressed my opinion on this subject in treating of rent, and have now only further to add, that rent is a creation of value, as I understand that word, but not a creation of wealth… that is to say, the necessaries, conveniences, and enjoyments of the society.

He also favorably quoted Jean-Baptiste Say for noting that,

“The earth... is not the only agent of nature which has a productive power; but it is the only one, or nearly so, that one set of men take to themselves to the exclusion of others; and of which, consequently, they can appropriate the benefits. The waters of rivers, and of the sea, by the power which they have of giving movement to our machines, carrying our boats, nourishing our fish, have also a productive power; the wind which turns our mills, and even the heat of the sun, work for us; but happily no one has yet been able to say, the ‘wind and the sun are mine, and the service which they render must be paid for.’”

Getting back to the question of how rent arises, Ricardo notes,

On the first settling of a country in which there is an abundance of rich and fertile land, a very small proportion of which is required to be cultivated for the support of the actual population, or indeed can be cultivated with the capital which the population can command, there will be no rent; for no one would pay for the use of land when there was an abundant quantity not yet appropriated, and, therefore, at the disposal of whosoever might choose to cultivate it.

To illustrate this, let us assume four grades of land. On the best land (green), a typical farmer can get four units of wealth with the same effort that would only get him three units on the second-best grade (yellow), two units on the third-best (tan), and only one unit on the poorest land (maroon). Naturally, the first farmer will take up the best land, and will have no rent to pay. Other farmers will do the same, until there is no more first-grade land.


average farmer




Yield: 4
Yield 3
Yield 2
Yield 1
Rent: 0



Wages:4



At that point, Ricardo notes that they will start taking up second-best land, which has a lower yield.

It is only, then, because land is not unlimited in quantity and uniform in quality, and because, in the progress of population, land of an inferior quality, or less advantageously situated, is called into cultivation, that rent is ever paid for the use of it [the best land]. When, in the progress of society, land of the second degree of fertility is taken into cultivation, rent immediately commences on that of the first quality, and the amount of that rent will depend on the difference in the quality of these two portions of land.

At this point, the natural wage goes down to 3, and the rental value of the best land becomes 1.


average farmeraverage farmeraverage farmer

average farmer

Yield: 4
Yield: 3
Yield 2
Yield 1
Rent: 1
Rent: 0


Wages:3
Wages: 3



Landlords can also drive up rents by holding land out of use. Holding some of the best land idle forces new settlers to resort to second-best land sooner than they would have had to naturally. This drives down wages and drives up rents. In the illustration below, everyone would have access to the best land for free if not for some land being held out of use. In Europe, feudal lords did this through the Enclosure Acts. In North America, it was done by politically connected speculators grabbing up land they could not use, and sometimes by people homesteading one parcel just long enough to qualify for ownership and then homesteading another. Artificially high rents caused by holding land out of use is called “rack rents.”


average farmerno tresspassnigaverage farmer

average farmer

Yield: 4
Yield: 3
Yield 2
Yield 1
Rent: 1
Rent: 0


Wages:3
Wages: 3


When land of the third quality is taken into cultivation, rent immediately commences on the second, and it is regulated as before by the difference in their productive powers. At the same time, the rent of the first quality will rise, for that must always be above the rent of the second by the difference between the produce which they yield with a given quantity of capital and labour. With every step in the progress of population, which shall oblige a country to have recourse to land of a worse quality, to enable it to raise its supply of food, rent, on all the more fertile land, will rise.

— David Ricardo

Again, not all the better land is “taken into cultivation,” but it is all claimed. The more land is taken up, even if it is not actually put to use, the more rents rise and wages fall.

average farmerno tresspassnigaverage farmer

average farmeraverage farmerno tresspassnig no tresspassnigaverage farmer
Yield: 4
Yield: 3
Yield 2
Yield 1
Rent: 2
Rent: 1
Rent: 0
Wages: 2
Wages: 2
Wages: 2

Finally, when farmers are pushed down to the worst land that is capable of sustaining life (the maroon colored land on the chart), base wages are pushed down to a bare minium, and everything else is rent.


average farmerno tresspassnigaverage farmer

average farmeraverage farmerno tresspassnig no tresspassnigaverage farmeraverage farmer average farmer
Yield: 4
Yield: 3
Yield 2
Yield: 1
Rent: 3
Rent: 2
Rent: 1 Rent: 0
Wages: 1
Wages: 1
Wages: 1 Wages:1

The problem of land monopoly would be obvious enough if the workers all had the same ability, but that is not the case. Some workers are more productive and some less. Consider a farmer whose skills get him twice the yield on any given land that the average farmer gets, and another who only gets half they yield of an average farmer. In the beginning, when the best land is available to all, the best farmer will get twice the wage of the average farmer, and four times the wage of the worst farmer. However, even the worst farmer produces twice what he needs to survive:

super farmer
average farmer poor farmer
Yield: 4x2=8
Yield: 4x1=4
Yield 4x½=2

Rent: 0
Rent: 0
Rent: 0
Wages: 8
Wages: 4
Wages: 2

However, once rent rise to monopoly levels, the best farmer can stil pay the highest rent and have more wages left over, while the worst farmer loses money by renting better land. He gets no wage at all on anything but the worst, most rent-free land.

super farmeraverage farmerpoor farmer

super farmeraverage farmerpoor farmer super farmeraverage farmerpoor farmer super farmeraverage farmerpoor farmer
Yield: 4x2=8
4x1=4
4x½=2
Yield: 3x2=6
3x1=3
3x½=1½
Yield 2x2=4
2x1=2
2x½=1
Yield: 1x2=2
1x1=1
1x½=
½
Rent: 3
Rent: 2
Rent: 1 Rent: 0
Wages: 5,1,-1
Wages: 4,1,-½ Wages: 3,1,0 Wages:2,1,½

A poor farmer who inherited the best land could still make a decent living, as he would have no rent to pay. However, he would get more from renting out the best land to a superior farmer than from working the land himself. As a result, the best farmers tend to end up on the best land, and the worst farmers on the worst land. The separate competition between the best farmers also affects rents. Where superior farmers only have to out-bid  average farmers, the rent of that land is not affected. However, once average farmers are driven off the best land, as in the chart below, superior farmers must bid against other superior farmers, and rent on the best land is further increased.

super farmerno tresspassnigsuper farmer

super farmeraverage farmerno tresspassnig no tresspassnigaverage farmeraverage farmer average farmerpoor farmer
Yield: 8
Yield: 6,3
Yield 2
Yield: 1, ½
Rent: 3 up to 4
Rent: 2
Rent: 1 Rent: 0
Wages: 5 down to 4
Wages: 4,1
Wages: 1 Wages:1, ½

Originally, when everyone had access to the best land rent-free, the superior farmer was getting twice what he is getting now. Still, he was only getting twice what the average farmer got and four times what the worst farmer got. Even though he is getting half as much now as he got then, he is now getting four times what the average farmer gets and eight times what the worst farmer gets, even if he has to pay rent.

But the differential gets worse. Let us introduce simple capital in the form of a plow. The plow can also double the yield for the same amount of labor. The plow maker could sell plows for one unit of wealth and still survive, but he doesn’t have to, just yet, if he is the only plow-maker. He can increase the yield of the superior farmer on the best land by eight, so he can charge 8 for his first plow.


super farmerno tresspassnigsuper farmer
plow
super farmeraverage farmerno tresspassnig no tresspassnigaverage farmeraverage farmer average farmerpoor farmer
Yield: 16,8
Yield: 6,3
Yield: 2
Yield: 1, ½
Plow Cost:8


Rent:4
Rent: 2 Rent: 1 Rent: 0
Wages: 4
Wages: 4,1
Wages: 1 Wages:1, ½

However, his high wage for making plows will attract other plow makers who will compete on price. As the price of plows comes down, all the superior farmers on superior land will start using plows. But will their wages increase? Maybe for a little while, but the prospect of higher wages will drive up rents, and the landlords will absorb the gain until the wages going to superior farmers returns to four.

super farmerno tresspassnigsuper farmer
plowplow
super farmeraverage farmerno tresspassnig no tresspassnigaverage farmeraverage farmer average farmerpoor farmer
Yield: 16
Yield: 6,3
Yield: 2
Yield: 1, ½
Plow Cost: 8 down to 7



Rent:
4 up to 5
Rent: 2 Rent: 1 Rent: 0
Wages: still 4
Wages: 4,1
Wages: 1 Wages:1, ½

When the cost of plows falls all the way to two, all the farmers on the second-best land and some of the farmers on the third-best land will use them, the productivity difference between the second and third best land doubles, and the rent increases to absorb it.

super farmerno tresspassnigsuper farmer
plowplow
super farmeraverage farmerno tresspassnig
plowplow
no tresspassnigaverage farmeraverage farmer
plow
average farmerpoor farmer
Yield: 16
Yield: 12,6
Yield: 4,2
Yield: 1, ½
Plow Cost: 2
Plow Cost: 2 Plow Cost: 2
Rent: 7 Rent: 3 up from 2 Rent: 1 Rent: 0
Wages: 7
Wages: 7,1
Wages: 1 Wages:1, ½

We showed four distinct qualities of land and three distinct qualities of farmer to simplify demonstrating the principle. In reality, there are unlimited gradations of land quality and farmer quality. The principle still applies, however. Every increase in population and every advance in technology increases competition for land and drives up rent.

If we focus only on the disparity between the best and worst farmers, we might think the injustice is in the best farmer getting seven times what the average farmer gets, and 14 times what the worst farmer gets. This is partly because the best farmer is on the most productive land, partly because he has access to capital that the worst farmer does not have, and partly because he is, after all, a much better farmer. If he also owns the land he is working and is paying rent to himself, he is getting 28 times what the worst farmer gets. This is what Marxists and other anti-capitalists focus on, but the the classical liberals and early progressives asked, where is all that rent going? The answer is that much of it goes to private landlords who may or may not also be farmers. As farmers, they are wealth producers, but landlords, as Adam Smith noted, “reap where they never sowed.” What if we share the rent on a per capita basis? Based on our example, we get the following results:

Sharing the Rent of Land in Use
2 farmers on best land:
2x7=14
2 farmers on second-best land
2x3=6
2 farmers on third-best land
2x1=2
2 farmers on poorest land
zero
Total rent
22
Number of farmers
8
Rent share per farmer
22÷8=2¾


super farmerno tresspassnigsuper farmer
plowplow
super farmeraverage farmerno tresspassnig
plowplow
no tresspassnigaverage farmeraverage farmer
plow
average farmerpoor farmer
Yield: 16
Yield: 12,6
Yield: 4,2
Yield: 1, ½
Plow Cost: 2
Plow Cost: 2 Plow Cost: 2
Rent: 7 Rent: 3 up from 2 Rent: 1 Rent: 0
Wages: 7
Wages: 7,1
Wages: 1 Wages:1, ½
Rent Share: 2¾
Rent Share: 2¾ Rent Share: 2¾ Rent Share: 2¾
Total: 9¾ Total: 9¾, 3¾ Total: 3¾ Total, 3¾, 3

In this scenario, the best farmers are only getting 3¼ times as much as the worst farmers, which is about the same ratio as when everyone had access to the best land. More importantly, the worst farmer is now getting three times what he needs to survive, while he had been getting only half what he needed to survive. But what about the land that is being held out of use for speculation? Shouldn’t they pay rent, too? What would that do to the rent shares?

Total Land Rent with Vacant Lots
2 farmers on best land:
2x7=14
1 best parcel held idle
1x7=7
2 farmers on second-best land
2x3=6
1 second-best parcel held idle 1x3=3
2 farmers on third-best land
2x1=2
1 third-best  parcel held idle 1x2=2
2 farmers on poorest land
zero
Total rent
34
Number of farmers
8
Rent share per farmer
34÷8=4¼

super farmerno tresspassnigsuper farmer
plowplow
super farmeraverage farmerno tresspassnig
plowplow
no tresspassnigaverage farmeraverage farmer
plow
average farmerpoor farmer
Yield: 16
Yield: 12,6
Yield: 4,2
Yield: 1, ½
Plow Cost: 2
Plow Cost: 2 Plow Cost: 2
Rent: 7 Rent: 3 up from 2 Rent: 1 Rent: 0
Wages: 7
Wages: 7,1
Wages: 1 Wages:1, ½
Rent Share: 4¼
Rent Share: 4¼ Rent Share: 4¼ Rent Share: 4¼
Total: 11¼ Total: 11¼, 5¼ Total: 5¼ Total, 5¼, 4¾

Now the rent share is much larger. However, those people holding prime land idle were only doing so because it imposed little or no cost on them. As the tax on the rental value of their land is gradually increased, they will let go of that land. Without  prime land being held idle, there is no need for anyone to resort to the poorest land. That means the rent goes down for everyone. The third best land no longer pays any rent, because nobody has to use the poorest land at all. Rent shares will be lower, but wages will be higher.


Total Rent when Vacant Lots Disappear
Farmers
Rent
3 farmers on best land:
3x4=12
3 farmers on second-best land
3x2=6
2 farmers on third-best land
zero
Total rent
18
Number of farmers
8
Rent share per farmer
18÷8=2½


super farmersuper farmersuper farmer
plowplowplow
average farmeraverage farmeraverage farmer
plowplowplow
average farmerpoor farmer
plow

Yield: 4x2x2=16
Yield: 3x1x2=6
Yield: 2x1x2=4, 2x½=1
Yield: 1
Plow Cost: 2
Plow Cost: 2 Plow Cost: 2
Rent: 4 Rent: 2 Rent: 0
Wages: 10
Wages: 2
Wages: 2, 1
Rent Share: 2½
Rent Share: 2½ Rent Share: 2½
Total: 12½ Total: 4½ Total: 4½, 3½

Now the rent share is lower, but wages are higher, and total return to the worker is higher. Even the poorest worker is getting more than he got when he had access to the best land rent-free.

It’s also important that total productivity is higher. There is just as much land out of use as before, but now it is the least productive land that is out of use. Giving the people access to the most productive land increases the productivity of the whole economy,  and sharing the rent gives the benefit of higher productivity to everyone.

Productivity Without Rent Sharing
2 farmers on best land:
2x16=32
1 best parcel held idle
0
2 farmers on second-best land
12+6=18
1 second-best parcel held idle 0
2 farmers on third-best land
4+2=6
1 third-best  parcel held idle 0
2 farmers on poorest land
1+½=1½
Total productivity
57½

Productivity With Rent Sharing
3 farmers on best land:
3x16=48
3 farmers on second-best land
3x6=18
2 farmers on third-best land
4+1=5
0 farmers on poorest land
0
Total productivity
71

This answers the objection that people want to make the poor richer by making the rich poorer. Rent sharing makes all wealth producers richer by making the economy more productive.

This means that a rent-sharing program can be gradually introduced at any level of government, national, provincial, county or municipal. It can even be incorporated into a for-profit land trust.

We used farming as an example because it is simple. However, per capita rents are higher in suburbs than on farms, and higher still in cities. The highest rents of all are in central business districts (CBDs). Thus a square yard of prime Manhattan land is worth more than an acre of New York State farmland, and 25% of Pittsburgh’s taxable land value is in its “Golden Triangle,” which occupies only 1% of the land. Those CBD rents are also the most monopolized by large corporate interests. Taxing land values and sharing the rents would not only enrich the productive people of the taxing district, but would spur the development of idle and grossly underused land like this vacant tract in Pittsburgh, which is across from its city hall and in the midst of skyscrapers. Taxing this land would cause it to be put to a better use and would increase productivity:

Grant Street Parking Lot

Indeed, wherever land value tax has been implemented, it has led to increased construction and economic growth. This was recognized in the Fortune article, “Higher Taxes that Promote Development.” While funding a per capita dividend with other taxes might hurt economic vitality, doing so with a land value tax would clearly increase it.

So far, we have been looking at the economic aspects of rent sharing. The moral aspects are just as compelling.


Comments:

 

Saving Communities
420 29th Street
McKeesport, PA 15132
United States
412.OUR.LAND
412.687.5263